This research is outlined as follows: Part II reviews PPP literature, in which the subsection 1 on PPP theoretical background highlights the law of one price and the role of international trade as crucial conditions for the existence of the parity condition. An overall picture about extant empirical literatures on PPP including Australian evidences is provided in subsection 2 and 3. From these reviews we develop our arguments about the impacts of trade and investment on the PPP s between Australia and its trading partners. Part III presents the hypothesis our research and the methodologies, models we use to test the hypothesis in details. Part IV describes and discuss about the data used in our research. The results of this research are reported and discussed in Part V. Conclusion is provided in Part VI; and Part VII proposes some direction for future research.
26 trang |
Chia sẻ: lvcdongnoi | Lượt xem: 2736 | Lượt tải: 0
Bạn đang xem trước 20 trang tài liệu How does ppp hold between australia and its trading partners, để xem tài liệu hoàn chỉnh bạn click vào nút DOWNLOAD ở trên
__________________________________________________________
THE AUSTRALIAN NATIONAL UNIVERSITY
School of Finance and Applied Statistics
Research Project in International Finance
_____________________________________________________________________
DANG H. PHAM
U4278723
Research Project in International Finance: 2007 Dang H. Pham
HOW DOES PPP HOLD BETWEEN
AUSTRALIA AND ITS TRADING
October the 26th, 2007
2
Research Project in International Finance: 2007 Dang H. Pham
Table of Contents
I. INTRODUCTION ......................................................................................... 4
II. LITERATURE REVIEW .............................................................................. 6
1. Theoretical background ......................................................................................... 6
2. Empirical evidences about PPP ............................................................................. 7
3. Australian evidence................................................................................................. 9
III. METHODOLOGY .................................................................................... 11
1. Test of PPP............................................................................................................. 11
2. Effects of trade and investment on PPP.............................................................. 12
IV. DATA ...................................................................................................... 13
V. RESULTS DISCUSSION.......................................................................... 15
1. PPP with 12 countries.......................................................................................... 15
2. Effect of trading and FDI on PPP ....................................................................... 20
VI. CONCLUSION ........................................................................................ 22
VII. FUTURE RESEARCH DIRECTIONS..................................................... 23
3
Research Project in International Finance: 2007 Dang H. Pham
I. INTRODUCTION
The interrelations between three major components of the international market
(international trade, foreign exchange and capital market) are explained by the
economic theories called the international parity conditions. It is considered to be
unique to the field of International Finance (Eiteman, Stonehill and Moffett
2006:102). Deriving from the Law of one price, the absolute form of purchasing
power parity (PPP) states that if the market is frictionless the price of identical
products and services should be the same in different markets. For instance, if the
price of the product in Australian dollar is PAUD, then the price of the identical
product in U.S. dollar (PUSD) should be equal to PAUD adjusted for exchange rate
(SUSD/AUD), or PAUD x SUSD/AUD = PUSD . Thus, the nominal exchange rate can be
simply expressed as the ratio of the two prices (SUSD/AUD = PUSD / PAUD). If this is not
the case, the arbitrageurs in an efficient market could make riskless profit by shipping
the goods from locations where the price is low to locations where the price is high
(Taylor and Taylor, 2004). They will trade the opportunity away and bring the
conditions back to “parity”. If the PPP holds perfectly the nominal exchange rate
adjusts to maintain a constant real exchange rate equal to 1. The relative form of PPP
involves only that the change in nominal exchange rate offsets the differential
between home and foreign price level.
While international trade plays a vital role in a PPP , obviously the market frictions
such as transportation cost, taxes, tariffs and duties, and non-tariff barriers such as
quotas and import licenses are the main causes of some deviations from PPP. In
recent years we have seen the emergence of multinational and bilateral free trade
arrangements where governments set the objectives to bust up trades by removing
trade barriers. Australia has joined WTO and signed free trade agreements with the
United States and Thailand in 2005, with Singapore in 2003 and with New Zealand
from 1993. It is now in negotiating Free Trade Agreements with other countries and
areas such as Japan, ASEAN, Malaysia, China, Chile and Gulf countries. This
research project tests the PPP between Australia and its trading partners over the
period from 1984 to 2006 and provides some insights on particular effects that the
level of bilateral trade and investment have on their PPP . Using quarterly of foreign
exchange rates and proxy for country price level (both consumer price index and
producer/whole sales price index) evidence from my sample shows that PPP holds for
4
Research Project in International Finance: 2007 Dang H. Pham
some countries while it does not hold for others. Further, the higher level of bilateral
trade significantly and positively associates with the higher level of PPP . Foreign
investment level is found to have positive impacts on PPP but not significantly.
This research is outlined as follows: Part II reviews PPP literature, in which the
subsection 1 on PPP theoretical background highlights the law of one price and the
role of international trade as crucial conditions for the existence of the parity
condition. An overall picture about extant empirical literatures on PPP including
Australian evidences is provided in subsection 2 and 3. From these reviews we
develop our arguments about the impacts of trade and investment on the PPP s
between Australia and its trading partners. Part III presents the hypothesis our
research and the methodologies, models we use to test the hypothesis in details. Part
IV describes and discuss about the data used in our research. The results of this
research are reported and discussed in Part V. Conclusion is provided in Part VI; and
Part VII proposes some direction for future research.
5
Research Project in International Finance: 2007 Dang H. Pham
II. LITERATURE REVIEW
1. Theoretical background
Economists widely believe that the PPP theory hold at least approximately because of
the possibility of the international goods market arbitrage. In the formal way, the PPP
theory states that the percentage change in the exchange rates over a given period
simply offset the difference in inflation rates in the countries concerned over the same
period. Therefore, in the relative form of PPP, according to Eiteman et al. (2006:105),
“if a country experiences a higher rate of inflation, and its exchange rate does not
change, then its goods prices will be relatively more expensive”. Eiteman et al.
(2006:105) also states that “if the spot exchange rate between two countries starts in
equilibrium, any change in differential rate of inflation between them tends to be
offset over the long run by an equal but opposite change in the exchange rate”.
Hence, the relative PPP is useful for forecasting the spot exchange (long run) rates
from the expected inflation rates in the two countries. The model is described as
follows:
t
f
t
h
fh
fh
t
S
SE
)1(
)1()(
/
0
/
π
π
+
+= (1.1) or (1.2) fhfhS ππ −=Δ /
Where: is the expected spot exchange rate at time t, is the current spot
exchange rate,
)( / fhtSE
fhS /0
hπ is the inflation rate in home country and fπ is the inflation rate in
foreign country. is the change in spot exchange rate in a period of time t. fhS /Δ
However, international goods markets are far less liquid than financial markets and
the frictions seem to be considerable and it is the fact that there is in existence goods
that fall outside the various range of homogeneous goods. Therefore, short-run
international arbitrage has only limited effect of leveling international goods market
prices (Rogoff, 1996).
While the traditional PPP theory holds that the real exchange rate should be constant
and equal to 1, there is another assumption of long-run deviations from PPP. Harrod
(1933), Balassa (1964) and Samuelson (1964) build their model of the equilibrium
exchange rate on the observation that rich countries tend to have higher price levels
than poor countries. This is because rich countries are relatively more productive in
the traded high-tech goods and they grow richer as a result. Income rises as a result of
6
Research Project in International Finance: 2007 Dang H. Pham
the higher productivity in tradable goods will cause price level to rise also. This effect
modeled by Harrod, Balassa and Samuelson seem to be stronger over time where data
show a strong positive relationship between income and price level. If this is true,
then the real exchange rate is not constant over time.
In general, as PPP theory is derived from the law of one price, its basic condition is
the perfect international trade of goods and services. If there is no trade, obviously no
PPP exists. The perfect trading market (without friction and transaction costs) is the
key assumption in PPP theory. In this research, an examination on PPP relation
between Australia and its different trading partners to find out the consistency and
inconsistency with the above-mentioned assumption is therefore necessary.
2. Empirical evidences about PPP
There has been a heightened level of extant literature on the validity of PPP. The
results of the PPP tests varies according to according to whether (i) price and
exchange rate levels (absolute PPP) or changes in prices and exchange rates (relative
PPP) are studied; (ii) individual commodity prices or nominal price levels are
employed; (iii) purely traded goods’ prices or non-traded as well as traded goods
prices are considered; (iv) bilateral or multilateral approach is adopted; and (v) the
short run or the long run is investigated (Rush and Husted, 1985). In the respect of
long-run or short-run validity of PPP, for example, evidence from Edler and Lehmann
(1983), Enders (1988) and Ardeni and Lubian (1991) reject long-run PPP. However,
Diebold, Husted and Rush (1991), Cheung and Lai (1993), Edison (1987), Frenkel
(1981), Branson (1981), Desai (1981), and Miller (1986) strongly support that the
PPP holds in the long run and poorly in the short-run. Cooper (1994) claims that the
main reasons for the inconclusive results are due to the difference in particular
currencies under consideration, the price indices used to measure price levels of
inflation, and the method of analysis employed.
Early empirical tests (mainly in the 1970s) find support for the long-run and
continuous PPP (Frankel, 1976 and1981). This might be partly due to the data of a
period of stable exchange rates (few years post-float after 1971- collapse of the
Bretton Woods Agreement). On the other hand, PPP deviates significantly from
equilibrium in the short-run PPP due to the sticky nominal prices (Dornbusch, 1976).
However, there is no evidence of how far do exchange rates deviate from the mean
and how fast they revert to the mean, knowing that mean reversion of exchange rates
7
Research Project in International Finance: 2007 Dang H. Pham
toward its mean is the key characteristic and necessary condition for long-run PPP to
hold (Taylor and Taylor, 2004). Studies employing unit root test of real exchange rate
(the null hypothesis is that real exchange rate follow a random walk) could not reject
the random walk (see, for example, Roll 1979);
Contemporary empirical studies of PPP are dominated by unit root tests with more
advanced techniques. Frankel ( 1986) tests the first order autocorrelation model for
the real exchange rates: tt eeee εδ +−=− − )~()~( 11 where e~ is the assumed
constant equilibrium real exchange rate and δ is the autocorrelation coefficient. If
δ >1 it is an explosive process; if δ =1, then exchange rates follow a random walk; if
δ <1, then there is mean reversion. The evidence from this test rejects the hypothesis
of random walk at 5% significant level. Abuaf and Jorion (1990) estimate a system of
univariate autoregressions and find in general that PPP hold in the long-run. Others
studies using longer data sets and more sophisticated models also reject the null
hypothesis of random walk (see, for example, Glenn, 1992; Dielbold, Husted
&Rush,1991; and Cheung and Lai, 1994). As evidence from many studies have
shown that exchange rates have mean reversion characteristics, it is desirable to know
how fast the exchange rates revert to the mean or in other words to what extent of
time horizon PPP holds? Reviews of Rogoff (1996) reveal that studies seem to agree
that the deviation from PPP real exchange rate has half-life of 3 to 5 years.
While some recent studies use non-linear dynamic models that allow for the
autoregressive coefficients to vary find supportive evidence of non-linear long-run
PPP. For example, Taylor, Peel and Sarno (2001) find support for non-linear mean-
reverting real exchange rates. They also find that ‘modest’ deviation of less than 5%
have half-life of less than 3 years while deviations greater than 5% have even shorter
half-life. Sarno and Valente (2006) test long-run PPP using complex non-linear
model. Their results indicate that long-run PPP does appear to hold. Further, PPP
deviations revert more quickly under floating exchange regimes. In contrast, other
latest studies on the validity of PPP even using advanced techniques still have
different results. For example, Alba and Papell (2007) examines the long-run PPP
using panel data methods to test for unit roots in the USD real exchange rates of 84
countries finds that PPP holds for European and Latin American countries but not for
Asian and African countries. Arghyrou and Gregoriou (2007) tests for long-run PPP
8
Research Project in International Finance: 2007 Dang H. Pham
using more sophisticated unit root test on G7 countries over the last 30 years. They
find that PPP does not hold in the long-run.
In general, PPP test appear to be a puzzle. The extremely high short-term volatility of
exchange rates hardly reconcile with the long-run PPP and the half-life of PPP
reversion of 3 to 5 years is too long to be caused by short-run sticky nominal prices
(Rogoff, 1996) states,. Perhaps the international goods market is not as integrated as
we think, with large trading frictions creating a ‘band of inaction’ that permits wild
fluctuation in nominal exchange rate with no effect on price levels (Rogoff, 1996;
Taylor and Taylor, 2004). Alba and Papell (2007) share the same view when they find
evidence that PPP is stronger in countries that have higher levels of trade, closer to
the US (physical distance), and countries characteristics affect PPP adherence. Based
on these finding, when testing PPP between Australia and its trading partners, this
paper hypothesizes that PPP hold better between Australia and its major trading
partners.
3. Australian evidence
In the Australia context, empirical evidence of PPP is also inclusive. For example,
Corbae and Oularis (1991) claims that PPP does not hold in long run for the
Australian dollar, as the data follow a random walk. Conversely, Olekalns and
Wilkins (1998), when re-examining the data used by Corbae and Oularis (1991), find
different results that the long-run PPP holds for Australian dollar. The research
conducted by Bhati and McCrae (2004) supports the long-run PPP when the
Australian dollar is used as the based currency in relation with the Asia-Pacific
trading partners of Australia. The exceptions include Singapore, Indonesia and New
Zealand with poor evidence of PPP. Koedijk, Schotman and Vandijk (1998: p.60)
point out that “there is substantive evidence that PPP holds for many currencies,
although not for every currency to the same extent”.
The only one thing that is clear from the evidences for Australia is that PPP varies
across its trading partners. It is our conjecture that the level of PPP depends on the
degree of trade relation between the host country and the foreign country. Hence, it is
deserved a comprehensive investigation in this research. This research project tests
PPP using the Australian dollar as a base currency with other 10 currencies selected
from countries classification by the Reserve Bank of Australia (RBA) based on trade
weights (described in Appendix 1). The test aims to find evidence which shows PPP
9
Research Project in International Finance: 2007 Dang H. Pham
holding better with higher trade weighted countries. Some abnormal cases rejected by
the test will be further discussed for appropriate reasons.
10
Research Project in International Finance: 2007 Dang H. Pham
III. METHODOLOGY
1. Test of PPP
The main objective of this study is to provide an overall understanding of how PPP
holds between Australia and its trading partners. We select the representing countries
categorize them into groups which have different trading levels with Australia. Test
of PPP is conducted for each country/currency and compare to each others and
between different groups.
We test the PPP using relative form. Based on the equation (1.2) we construct the
regression model as follows:
εππβα +−+=Δ )(/ fhfhtS (2.1)
hπ and fπ are home and foreign quarterly inflation rates respectively (based on CPI
change); and is the quarterly change in the nominal exchange rate. fhtS
/Δ
Under the relative form (equation 1.2) the condition for PPP to hold is that the
estimated values of α = 0 and β = 1 (estimated from 2.1). We hypothesize as
follows:
H0: PPP holds or α = 0 and β = 1
HA: PPP does not hold or α is different from 0 and β is different from 1
We use F-statistics to test the null that α = 0 and β = 1 jointly (Wooldridge
2006:150-160). F-statistics are calculated using the error terms of restricted model
and error terms of unrestricted model as follows:
)1/(
/)
−−
−=
knSSE
qSSESSEF
ur
urr
The unrestricted model is the model (2.1)
Under the null hypothesis model of (2.1) becomes: this is
called the restricted model.
εππ +−=Δ )(/ fhfhtS
k is the number of variables in model (2.1);
n is the number of observation,
11
Research Project in International Finance: 2007 Dang H. Pham
q is the number of variables restricted.
If F-statistic > critical value then we reject the null hypothesis to accept the
alternative. Otherwise, we cannot reject the null hypothesis and conclude PPP holds.
For the purpose of ranking the level of PPP between different trading partners, we
also look at p value and R-squared as supplementing measures.
2. Effects of trade and investment on PPP
Since the actual relationship between exchange rates and price levels often deviate
from the parity and tend to revert from time to tine. Reasonably, the more exchange
rates deviate from the theoretical PPP the less PPP holds for that currency. We
measure the deviation from the equation of relative form of PPP as follows:
t
f
t
h
fh
t
fh
t
S
SonPPPdeviati
)1(
)1(
/
1
/
π
π
+
+−=
−
(2.2)
hπ and fπ are home and foreign quarterly inflation rates respectively (based on CPI
change); and and are exchange rates at time the quarterly change in the
nominal exchange rate at time t and t-1.
fh
tS
/
1−
fh
tS
/
Effects of trade and investments on PPP is estimated from the regression of PPP
deviations against annual trade weights and foreign direct investment level in the
following model:
tInvestmentTradePPPdev εβββ +++= 210. (2.3)
The sign and the significance of 1β and 2β estimated from (2.3) indicate the effect of
trade and foreign investment on PPP .
12
Research Project in International Finance: 2007 Dang H. Pham
IV. DATA
Among Australia trading partners, we select 12 countries/currencies that their trading
weights range from the high to low across the sample period from 1984 – 2005 (See
Table 1) for our sample.
Table 1. List of currencies of Australia’s trading partner countries selected for
PPP test. The trade weights represent the level of trading between that
country and Australia.
No. Currency Average Trade Weights (%)
1 Japanese yen 16.95
2 Chinese renminbi 8.92
3 European euro 12.81
4 United States dollar 14.62
5 South Korean won 6.16
6 Singapore dollar 4.25
7 New Zealand dollar 5.71
8 United Kingdom pound sterling 5.23
9 Malaysian ringgit 3.01
10 Indonesian rupiah 2.99
11 Canadian dollar 1.57
12 Swiss franc 0.78
(According to trade weights table announced annually by RBA)
The quarterly nominal exchange rates of Australian dollar to the 12 currencies for the
period from 1984 to 2006 are collected from the Website of the Reserve Bank of
Australia. We obtain quarterly Consumer Price Index (CPI) and Producer Price Index
(PPI)/Wholesale Price Index (WPI)1 (from hereon PPI and CPI are referred to as PPI
for convenience) of the 12 countries for the same period from Datastream-economics
database.
fh
tS
/Δ is calculated from the quarterly nominal exchange rates between the Australian
dollar and the foreign currency. The selection of quarterly data deriving from the
needs that time interval should be long enough for the differences in countries’
inflation rates to take effect on the corresponding exchange rates. Changes in nominal
exchange rates are estimated from the following formula:
1
1
−
−−
t
tt
S
SS
. Inflation rates
1 WPI is used instead of PPI for countries that PPI is not available (for example Australia)
13
Research Project in International Finance: 2007 Dang H. Pham
are measured using CPI and PPI by the following formula:
1
1
−
−−
t
tt
CPI
CPICPI
and
1
1
−
−−
t
tt
PPI
PPIPPI
. We use both CPI and PPI for our PPP test because some countries’
trading relationship with Australia may rely on industrial go than consumer goods.
Then, theoretically, the parity conditions are guaranteed by the arbitrage activities in
industrial goods markets rather than consumer markets. Hence, PPI is better than CPI
to reflect the PPP with those countries. This is also consistent with the extant
literature that several studies use both CPI and whole sale price index (WPI) (See, for
example, Chinn 1999). Further, In and Sugema (1995) and Bhati and McCrae (2004)
indicate that there is no evidence determining whether CPI or WPI is better.
The exports and imports between Australia and the 12 countries are collected from
the database of UNCTAD. Foreign Direct Investment (FDI) into Australia and from
Australia to the 12 countries are collected from database of UNDP. However, the FDI
data are only available from 1992 to 2003. Therefore, we do the test of the effect of
trade on PPP separately first. And then we do the second test to see the effects of
both trade and FDI on PPP in a multivariate regression using data from 1992-2003.
The time-period of data in this case is quite short for an examination of long-run PPP
we do not expect to obtain significant results from this test. However, the signs of the
effects are also helpful for the future research direction.
14
Research Project in International Finance: 2007 Dang H. Pham
V. RESULTS DISCUSSION
1. PPP with 12 countries
Table 2 reports results of our regression model (2.1) using OLS method. CPI changes
are used as proxy for the inflation rates in home (Australia) and foreign countries. If
we set 5% significance level to reject the null hypothesis, the results indicate that we
reject PPP for 9 countries. PPP holds only for Malaysia, United States and United
Kingdom. Table 2 also ranks the countries from high level of PPP to low level (even
insignificant). PPP with New Zealand is not rejected if we set the significance level
at 10%, showing that New Zealand is quite close to United Kingdom in the level of
PPP . It should be noted that Japan, which is always the biggest trading partner of
Australia, shows an insignificant PPP and relatively weaker than many smaller
trading partner. Although, China is the second largest trading partner of Australia
now, PPP with China is at lowest level. This may be due to the Chinese exchange rate
regime.
Table 2. α and β are estimated from equation using
OLS method. CPI is used to measure the inflation rates. F-statistics are calculated by
the formula
εππβα +−+=Δ )(/ fhfhtS
)1/(
/)
−−
−=
knSSE
qSSESSEF
ur
urr which used for testing α =0 and β =1 jointly. P-
value of F-statistics shows the probability of having the F-statistics above the F
critical value.
Country α β F-statistics P-value
Malaysia 0.0026 0.37 2.14 0.123372
United States -0.0048 1.51 2.26 0.110163
UK -0.0041 0.35 2.27 0.109906
New Zealand 0.0012 1.64 2.72* 0.071340
Canada -0.0063 1.10 4.92** 0.009464
Korea 0.001 -0.30 6.19** 0.003092
EU 0.0096 -3.05 6.33** 0.005749
Switzerland -0.0046 -0.49 13.17** 0.000010
Japan -0.0151 0.974 13.44** 0.000008
Singapore -0.0085 0.57 14.30** 0.000004
Indonesia 0.0397 0.48 18.84** 0.000000
China 0.011 -0.35 27.70** 0.000000
* Significant at 10% level * * Significance at 1% level
15
Research Project in International Finance: 2007 Dang H. Pham
PPP is rejected with many countries as reported in Table 2 when CPI is used to
estimate the inflation rates in both countries. The CPI index reflects the price level of
a basket of consumer goods. The extent to which CPI represents a country general
price level depends on the market structure that country. Also, the degree to which
any differences in CPI level between two countries depends on the size of the trading
on consumer goods relative with other foreign trade markets (e.g. industrial goods
markets). It is reasonably for us to do another test that use PPI index as proxy for
country price level. We expect that the industrial goods market may be more
influential on foreign exchange rates fluctuation than the consumer goods market.
The results of the second test using PPI changes as proxy for the inflation rates are
reported in Table 3.
Table 3. α and β are estimated from equation using
OLS method. PPI/WPI is used to measure the inflation rates. F-statistics are
calculated by the formula
εππβα +−+=Δ )(/ fhfhtS
)1/(
/)
−−
−=
knSSE
qSSESSEF
ur
urr which used for testing α =0 and
β =1 jointly. P-value of F-statistics shows the probability of having the F-statistics
above the F critical value.
Country α β F-statistics P-value
Korea 0.004 1.085 0.36 0.698979
Singapore 0.0041 1.126 0.82 0.444955
United States 0.001 0.816 0.94 0.393484
Malaysia 0.006 1.054 0.98 0.379556
Japan -0.0016 0.673 1.41 0.249991
China 0.0162 0.914 1.73 0.184897
Switzerland -0.0025 0.61 2.03 0.137938
United Kingdom -0.0026 0.63 2.58* 0.081697
Canada -0.0008 0.638 5.56** 0.005381
New Zealand -0.0021 0.373 11.04** 0.000055
EU 0.0033 -0.013 12.26** 0.000195
Indonesia -0.0107 2.047 35.30** 0.000000
* Significance at 10% level
* * significance at 1% level
16
Research Project in International Finance: 2007 Dang H. Pham
The results in Table 3 indicate that only PPP is rejected for only 5 countries (at 5%
significance level) or only for 4 countries if 10% significance level is set. Overall, the
PPP holds better when our test use PPI as proxy for price level.
In particular, the PPP holds better with CPI for some countries (New Zealand and
Canada), while for almost others, PPP holds better with PPI (e.g. Korea, Singapore,
Japan and China).
We argue that industrial goods market with Australia may have much more influential
on foreign exchange rate than the consumer goods market. Figure 1 and Figure 2
present the structure of Australia’ foreign trade.
Figure 1 Australia Imports in two different markets – Industrial and Consumer
Australia Imports
0
5000
10000
15000
20000
25000
30000
35000
Ma
r-8
4
Ma
r-8
6
Ma
r-8
8
Ma
r-9
0
Ma
r-9
2
Ma
r-9
4
Ma
r-9
6
Ma
r-9
8
Ma
r-0
0
Ma
r-0
2
Ma
r-0
4
Ma
r-0
6
cu
rr
en
t p
ric
e
Consumer
Industrial
Source: RBA
Figure 2 Australia Exports in two different markets – Industrial and Consumer
17
Research Project in International Finance: 2007 Dang H. Pham
Australia Exports
0
5000
10000
15000
20000
25000
30000
35000
Ma
r-8
4
Ma
r-8
6
Ma
r-8
8
Ma
r-9
0
Ma
r-9
2
Ma
r-9
4
Ma
r-9
6
Ma
r-9
8
Ma
r-0
0
Ma
r-0
2
Ma
r-0
4
Ma
r-0
6
cu
rr
en
t p
ri
ce
Consumer
Industrial
Source: RBA
It is clearly indicated in Figure 1 and 2 that the industrial goods market dominates
both Australia’s import and export trading activities. This fact explains, to some
extent, why in general PPP holds better when PPI is used as proxy for the price
levels.
For country specific cases, countries such as New Zealand and Canada may have the
same comparative advantages as Australia (natural resources and agriculture
products). Therefore, their industrial markets with Australia are less important than
consumer market, which explains the worse PPP found when using PPI as proxy. Our
results confirm the findings in previous studies (see, for example, Bhati and McCrae,
2004; and Cooper, 1994).
One important reason for the rejections of PPP in both tests using CPI and PPI is the
impact of transaction costs. Sercu, Uppal and Hulle (1995:1317) state that “In reality,
though, commodity trade is costly. As a result of these costs, international imbalances
between marginal utilities will be left uncorrected as long as they are sufficiently
small relative to the cost of shipping”. Hence, the long distance between Australia
and America, Europe could partly imply relatively higher transactions costs so as to
negatively impact the PPP .
Furthermore, capital mobility (excluding FDI) is recently considered a major force
that may distort the PPP since a huge amount of capital assets transactions creates a
18
Research Project in International Finance: 2007 Dang H. Pham
great impact on exchange rates. The CPI indices never reflect international capital
transactions. Cooper (1994: p.170) claims that the reason that PPP poorly explains
exchange rates is that:
“...it ignores capital flows. In recent years, capital has been free to move from country
to country. Cross border trade in financial assets swamps foreign exchange transactions
in goods and services. It is estimated that almost US$ 100 trillion equivalent is traded
annually on foreign exchange markets and it is twenty times the value of the World
trade in goods.”
United States and United Kingdom are the largest sources and destination of capital
mobility (excluding FDI) in and out of Australia. This could partly explain why they
are larger trading partners than other countries but PPP levels are lower. Figure 1 and
Figure 2 show the level of capital (excluding FDI) mobility between Australia and
some foreign countries.
Figure 1: Foreign Investment in Australia, 31 December 2005
(Source: Australian Bureau of Statistics Website)
Figure 2: Australian Investment Abroad, 31 December 2005.
(Source: Australian Bureau of Statistics Website)
19
Research Project in International Finance: 2007 Dang H. Pham
2. Effect of trading and FDI on PPP
The PPP theory assumes the law of one price in an efficient international trade market
as the fundamental conditions for a parity relationship (The law of one price works).
Reasonably, the higher trade levels imply a more efficient market then the better PPP
we can expect. This research paper also examines the effect of trading between
Australia and its trading partners from 1984 to 2005 on their PPP .
FDI also represents the capital mobility effect; however, FDI is very different from
the portfolio capital investment in that it normally goes with the increase of trade and
less liquidity. Therefore, we expect that FDI may have positive effect on PPP . This
research will also make an effort to test the effect of FDI on PPP . Results are
reported in Table 4 below.
Table 4. Present results of regression PPP deviation against trade and FDI. Since we
can collect more data on trade than FDI, effect of trade on PPP is separately tested
using data from 1984-2005. The result shows that relative trading level significantly
(at 5%) increase the PPP . Then we examine effects of trade and FDI on PPP using
data from 1992-2003. We find no significant results. However, the sign of
coefficients show that all trade and FDI seem to increase the PPP .
Data Period Trade FDI
1984-2005
-0.09
( 2.2 )* NA
1992-2003
-0.09
( 1.22 )
-0.006
( 0.45 )
* Significant at 5%
Results in Table 4 are obtained when PPP deviations are regressed against the trade
weights level from 1984 to 2005 using Pooled cross-sectional data for all 12 countries
together. The negative significant at 5% of trade factor indicates that relative trade
level does decrease the PPP deviation. In other words, relative trade levels
significantly increase the level of PPP .
We can not collect enough FDI data for the full range of our study period. In fact, the
data are only available from 1992-2003 (UNCTAD database). Hence, we test the
20
Research Project in International Finance: 2007 Dang H. Pham
effect of trade and investment in a multivariate regression using data only from 1992-
2003. Results from this test are not significant for all trade level and FDI. This could
be due to the lack of data for our long-run PPP study. However, the sign of the
coefficients of trade and FDI indicate that FDI seems to have positive impact on the
PPP .
21
Research Project in International Finance: 2007 Dang H. Pham
VI. CONCLUSION
Empirical studies so far still hold inconclusive view on the existence of PPP in the
real world even for the long-run. Some issue relating to testing PPP remains a puzzle.
We test the PPP between Australia and its 12 trading partners for the period from
1984 to 2006. The results reject PPP for 9 countries when we use CPI changes as
proxy for inflation rates. However, when PPI is used instead, PPP is rejected for only
5 countries with 5% significance level.
The domination of trading in industrial goods market, to some extent, explains why
PPP holds better with PPI.
In country specific level, we find that PPP hold better with CPI for some countries
(New Zealand, Canada). Other countries show better PPP with PPI. The same
competitive advantages of New Zealand and Canada explain that abnormal results.
Investigation on the effect of level of trade on PPP deviation reports that trading
decrease the level of PPP deviation or, in the other words, increases PPP. This effect
is found significant at 5%.
FDI seem to have positive effect on the level of PPP where our evidence shows a
negative sign against PPP deviations but far to be significant. We suggest that the
insignificant result for FDI may have its reason in the shortage of Data which allows
us to conduct the test only from 1992-2003, too short for a long-run PPP test.
22
Research Project in International Finance: 2007 Dang H. Pham
VII. FUTURE RESEARCH DIRECTIONS
Since PPP is known theoretically to be affected by many other factors such as the
transaction costs, the difference in levels of income, portfolio capital investment
activities, and further studies could improve the results by doing more comprehensive
test on the effect of those factors on the level of PPP .
Consumer goods markets often imply the country specific cultural characteristic, thus
income cases consumer goods in one market can not be used in other market. In that
case the law of one price hardly works well in practice. Take Japan consumer goods
market for example, there are a lot of consumer products that are produced uniquely
for the Japanese market and can not be use outside Japan. Therefore, future studies on
PPP can be interesting to model the cultural factors.
23
Research Project in International Finance: 2007 Dang H. Pham
References
Adler, M. and Lehman, B. (1983) Deviations from Purchasing Power Parity in the
Long Run. Journal of Finance 38 (December 1983), 1471-1487.
Alba, J. & Papell, D. (2007) PPP and Country Characteristics: Evidence From Panel
Data Tests, Journal of Development Economics, vol. 83, pp. 240-51.
Ardeni, P. G. and Lubian, D. (1991) Is there trend reversion in purchasing power
parity?. European Economic Review, 35, p. 1035-1055.
Arghrou, M. & Gregoriou, G. (2007) Testing for PPP Correcting for Non-linearity
Using the Wide Bootstrap, Economic Letter, vol. 95, pp. 285 -90.
Australian Bureau of Statistics (2006) International Investment Position, Australia:
Supplementary Country Statistics, 2005.
[Accessed
28 September 2006]
Balassa, B. (1964) The PPP Doctrine: A Reappraisal, Journal of Political Economy,
vol. 72, no. 6, pp. 584-96.
Bhagwati, J. (1984) Are Services Cheaper in Poor Countries, Economic Journal, vol.
94(347), pp. 279-86.
Branson, W. H. (1981) Comment: The Collapse of Purchasing Power Parity during
the 1970’s. European Economic Review, 16(May 1981), p. 167-171.
Bhati, S. and McCrae, M. (2004) Purchasing Power parity: Evidence from Asia
Pacific Countries. Journal of American Academy of Business, Sept. 2004, 5,1/2,
p.210.
Chinn, M. D. (1999) Measuring Misalignment: Purchasing Power Parity and East
Asian Currencies. IMF Working Paper. WP/99/120.
Cooper, J. B. (1994) Purchasing Power Parity: a cointegration analysis of the
Australian, News Zealand and Singapore currencies. Applied Economics
Letter,1994,1,167-171.
Cheung, Y. W. and Kon, S., L. (1993) A fractional cointegration analysis of
purchasing power parity. Journal of Business and Econmic Statistics, Vol.11(1993)
103-112.
Cheung, Y. & Lai, K. (1994) Mean Reversion in Real Exchange Rate, Economic
Letters, vol. 46, no. 3, pp. 251-56.
Corbae, D. and Oularis, S. (1991) A test of long run purchasing power parity allowing
for structural breaks. Economics Record, Vol.67(1991) 26-33.
Cumby, R & and Obstfeld, M. (1984) International Interest Rate and Price level
Linkages under Flexible Exchange Rates: A Review of Recent Evidence, in Exchange
Rate Theory and Practice, J & Marston, C eds, University of Chicago Press, Chicago.
Desai, M. (1981) Testing Monetarism, London: Frances Printer.
Diebold, F. X., Husted, S. and M., Rush (1991) Real exchange rate under gold
standard. Journal of Political Economy, 99(1991) 1252-1271.
24
Research Project in International Finance: 2007 Dang H. Pham
Dornbusch, R (1976) Expectation and Exchange Rate Dynamics, Journal of Political
Economy, vol. 84, no. 6 , pp. 1167-76.
Edison, H. J. (1987) Purchasing Power Parity in the Long Run: A Test of the
Dollar/Pound Exchange Rate (1890-1978). Journal of Money, Credit and Banking,
Vol.19, No.3(August 1987), p. 376-387.
Enders, W. (1988) ARIMA and Cointegration Tests of PPP under Fixed and Flexible
Exchange Rate Regimes. Review of Economics and Statistics 70(August 1998), p.
504-508.
Eiteman, Stonehill and Moffett (2006) International Business Finance (6thEddition).
Sydney: Longman
Frankel, J. A. (1981) The Collapse of Purchasing Power Parities during the 1970s,
European Economic Review, 16 (November 1981), p. 145-165.
In, F. and Sugema, I. (1995) Testing Purchasing Power Parity in a multivariate
frameworks. Applied Economics, Vol. 27 (1995), p 891-899.
Koedijk, K. G., Schotman P. C. and Vandijk, M. A. (1998) The re-emergence of PPP
in the 1990s, Journal of International Money and Finance, 17(1998) 51-56.
Miller, S. (1984) Purchasing Power Parity and Relative Price Variability Evidence
from the 1970s. European Economic Review, 26 (December 1984), p. 353-367.
Olekalns, N. and Wilkins, N. (1998) Re-examining the evidence for long-run
purchasing power parity. The Economic Record, 74, p. 54-61.
Rogoff, K (1996) The Purchasing Power Parity Puzzle, Journal of Economic
Literature, vol. 34, pp. 647-68.
Roll, R. (1979) Violation of PPP and Their Implication For Efficient International
Commodity Markets, in International Finance and Trad, Samat, M. and Szego, K
eds, Ballinger Press, Cambridge, pp. 133-76.
OECD Stat. (2006) CPIs all items
[Extracted on
21 September 2007]
Rush, M. and Husted, S.(1985) Purchasing power parity in the long run. Canadian
Journal of Economics, 18, 137-145.
Sarno, L. & Valente, G. (2006) Deviation From PPP Under Different Exchange Rate
Regimes: Do They Revert and If So, How?, Journal of Banking and Finance, vol. 30,
pp. 3147-69.
Sercu, P., Uppal, R. and C. Van Hulle (1995) The exchange rate in the presence of
transaction costs: Implication for test of Purchasing Power Parity. The Journal of
Finance, Vol. 50, No. 4. (Sep., 1995), 1309-1319.
Taylor, M. P. and McMahon, P. C. (1998) Long Run Purchasing Power Parity in the
1920s. European Economic Review, 32 (1998), 179-197.
Taylor, A. & Taylor, M. (2004) The Purchasing Power Parity Debates, Journal of
Economic Perspectives, vol. 18, no. 4, pp. 135-58.
Taylor, M., Peel, D & Sarno, L (2001) Non-linear Mean-reversion in Real Exchange
Rates: Toward a Solution to the Purchasing Power Parity Puzzle, International
Economic Review, vol. 42(4), pp. 1015-42.
25
Research Project in International Finance: 2007 Dang H. Pham
The Reserve Bank of Australia (2006) Exchange Rates Since 1983
[Accessed 25
September 2007]
26
Các file đính kèm theo tài liệu này:
- How does ppp hold between australia and its trading partners.pdf